Non Gamstop Sports Betting SitesNon Gamstop UK Betting SitesNon Gamstop CasinosNon Gamstop CasinosNon Gamstop CasinosNon Gamstop Casinos
The Professional
Contractors Group
Join the PCG
  home / judicial review / Gerald Barling QC - Speaking Notes Part 2    
Appeal Updates - December 2001
 
 
 
 
 
 

Gerald Barling QC - Speaking Notes Part 2.

This part of the extracts from Gerald Barling QC's, speaking notes which have been renumbered from the originals. Part 1 is in the archive on the left.

22. Far from being a general measure, therefore, IR35 is on all fours with cases such as those set out in paragraph 10 above which all have the characteristic that one group of undertakings was favoured over another, competing group of undertakings.


Positive and negative aids

24. At the time of the hearing before him, and the filing of the appellants appeal, there have been no case to come before the European court which raised the issue of what Burton J termed a “negative aid”. The only authority was the UK case of Lunn Poly …….ultimately the question was, as Lord Woolf stated, whether “you have the position of one body of tax payers receiving a benefit which another body of tax payers does not receive”.

25. Recently, however, the European Court has decided the case of Ferring which confirms the approach in Lunn Poly and which is even more similar to the present case.

26. Ferring concerned the adoption of legislation which imposed a particular tax burden on a specific defined group of undertakings (pharmaceutical companies selling directly). The legislation did not impose that burden on another competing group of undertakings (wholesale distributors of pharmaceutical products). Following reasoning almost identical to that in Lunn Poly, AG Tizzano and the courts found that the non-imposition of the same tax on the wholesale distributors conferred upon them a selective advantage.

27. Just as in both Lunn Poly and Ferring the IR35 legislation imposes a tax burden on a defined group of undertakings: companies defined as intermediaries which supply contracting services…..The legislation does not impose the same burden on a group of undertakings; non-intermediary companies supplying exactly the same contracting services. Just as in both LP and Ferring the two groups of undertakings are in competition.

28. The present case therefore merits exactly the same result as in Lunn Poly and Ferring; that the restriction of IR35 update to intermediaries companies and the exclusion of the appellants competitors (large contracting service providers) from this new unfavourable regime constitutes a selective advantage to the latter.

Pragmatic test

29. ……It is common ground that the concept of pragmatism cannot mean that there is a discretion in the evaluation of state aid under Article 87(1): no such discretion exists.

30. If that is the case then it must be asked what the concept of pragmatism adds to analysis……the test of state aid is a legal test set out in case law and Commission guidance. If the legal criteria of state aid are satisfied, then the measure is unlawful unless notified to the Commission; there is no room for any further test of pragmatism or common sense which could change the result of that analysis.

WTO Agreement on Subsidies and Countervailing Measures (SCM)

31. The Commissioners rely finally, on the SCM agreement. They argue that it can 1) it can provide an informative analogy and 2) under that agreement IR35 would not be a countervailable subsidy.

32. They are wrong in both respects……….


FREE MOVEMENTS

35. The appellants submit that IR35 infringes the free movement rules of Articles 39, 43 and 49. The application of these provisions is a well-known two stage test as accepted by Burton J.
a) do the measures constitute a prima facie infringement of one or more of the provisions;
b) if so the onus is on the member state to show that the restriction is both justified and proportionate.

36. In essence, the learned judge found that there was no prima facie infringement of Articles 39 and 43 and that there was a prima facie infringement of Article 49 but that it was justified and proportionate. The Commissioners assert additionally that there was not even a prima facie infringement of Article 49.

37. The appellants case is that the general approach of Burton J was incorrect; that IR35 constitutes a prima facie infringement of Articles 39, 43 and 49; that it was not justified; and that in any event it does not satisfy the requirement of proportionality.

The impediment to free movement

38. The appellants evidence was that the IR35 provisions are so prohibitive and discriminatory and creates such intolerable uncertainty as to employment and tax status that they deter service contractors in other member states from exercising their free movement rights…….

40. ……the measures in issue here are genuinely non-discriminatory on the grounds of nationality but impede free movement as described above……this kind of rule has been termed a ‘neutral’ restriction on free movement.

42. ……general principles make clear that there is no requirement that the measure involves discrimination or dislocation, whether in Articles 39, 43 or 49. On the contrary all three provisions include cases of neutral restrictions on free movement.

43. Burton J held that while Article 49 did extend to neutral restrictions, Articles 39 and 43 did not.

44. This is clearly contrary to the case set out above which does not differentiate between the three provisions.

Article 39 (workers)

45. Burton J held that IR35 did not infringe Article 39 on the grounds that the case law on this provision only covered cases of discrimination on grounds of nationality or discrimination on grounds of dislocation.

46. However, the case law on Article 39 has consistently made clear that neither discrimination on grounds of nationality, or discrimination on grounds of dislocation.

Article 43 (establishment)

51. The learned judge held that IR35 did not infringe Article 43 on the grounds that the case law on this provision only covered cases of discrimination on grounds of nationality or discrimination on grounds of dislocation. This made the same error of law as in the case of Article 39.

52. Equally, as with Article 39 this conclusion is wholly incorrect.

Article 49 (services)

55. By contrast with his approach to Articles 39 and 43, Burton held that the neutral IR35 provisions did arguably amount to a restriction under Article 49…..the Commissioners contest this conclusion.


No requirement on total prohibition on supply of services

65 The Commissioners second argument is that the cases cited by the appellants “concern the total prohibition on supply of services”, which they accepts is manifestly a restriction on the supply of services.

67 … the application of Article 49 is not restricted in either of the ways contended for by the commissioners.

Justification

68 Burton held and the Commissioners have contended that even if an infringement of free movement rules exists, the measures are justified.

69 It is common ground that the Treaty and the case-law of the court establish two categories of justification for a restriction of free movement.

70 The first category is that of justification on the grounds of public policy…

71 The second category is a judicially-developed justification … where the court will permit certain restrictions to be justified on the grounds of “imperative requirements in the public interest”.

72 This second category of justification is relied upon by the commissioners in the present case.

73 Burton held and the commissioners contend that the imperative requirements/overriding reasons justification can include prevention of tax avoidance and/or diminution in tax revenues. The appellants submit however that such justification is not in any case a permissible ground of justification for a restriction of free movement rights, whether concerning workers, establishment or services.

74 The dispute between the parties centres on three questions:

a) whether as a general principle economic aims may constitute imperative requirements/overriding reasons in the general interest.
b) whether specifically tax avoidance and/or diminution in tax revenue may constitute imperative requirements/overriding reasons in the general interest.
c) whether in the alternative the commissioners may rely on an equal treatment justification.

General principle: economic aims

75 Both categories of justification … are subject to the qualification that the justification cannot serve economic ends.

79 It is now established that the qualification … applies not only to the Treaty derogations, but also to the judicial justifications of imperative requirements/overriding reasons.

80 The commissioners ONLY attempt at answering this point is to criticise the appellants for “failing to distinguish between the movement of goods, workers and services” and to claim that none of the cases referred to concerned legislation against tax avoidance which discriminated neither on the grounds of nationality or dislocation.

81 This entirely misses the point. The statements made by the court… are unequivocal in applying generally to ALL the fundamental freedoms.

Tax avoidance and diminution in tax revenue

83 …the court has drawn a distinction between certain types of tax measures which may or may not be legitimately justified on the grounds of public interest.

84 On the one hand the court has never denied that a member state may legitimately adopt measures to ensure the proper enforcement of its laws… Equally a member state may adopt measures to prevent ILLEGAL ACTIVITIES such as tax evasion or tax fraud.

85 On the other hand a member state may NOT justify a restriction on the grounds of raising revenue or preventing (legal) tax avoidance activities.

87… it is manifest that … the specific rejection of tax avoidance measures applies generally to any measure which is contrary to a fundamental freedom, whether goods, workers, establishment or services.

88 The commissioners dispute this…

90 The stark difference between the state aid and the free movement provisions lies in the fact that by its nature an aid is a “unmarketlike advantage” … In order to prove that a measure is not an aid, therefore, the members state MUST show that the measure is economically justified.

91 …the court has consistently asserted that economic aims CANNOT justify interference with the fundamental Treaty provisions on free movement.

93 The commissioners third argument consists of an entirely incomprehensible series of assertions …

94 …it should be noted at the outset that the commissioners entirely confuse fiscal supervision, fiscal cohesion and tax avoidance…. The one and only justification put forward has consistently related to tax avoidance.

98 The commissioners can therefore not avoid the conclusion that a measure which restricts a fundamental Treaty freedom may not be just be justified on the grounds of either tax avoidance or diminution in tax revenue.

Equal treatment

99 As a “last shot” the commissioners in their skeleton argument argue that the aim of the contested legislation is not simply to prevent a reduction in tax revenues but is also intended to ensure equality of treatment.

100 As is evident from the commissioners failure to adduce any authority for this proposition a reference to “equality of treatment” has not ever been recognised as an imperative requirement of overriding reason which may justify an infringement of a fundamental Treaty freedom.

101 … the appellants submit that on the contrary there are strong reasons against allowing such a justification.

102… Even if permissible in law, however, the claim of justification on this ground is simply untenable on the facts. Regarding the situation pre-IR35, the indisputable fact is that all companies providing contracting services were taxed according to the same rules whether they were small, medium or large. The difference in treatment occurs post-IR35.

103 Moreover, the evidence shows that the legislation far from levelling the playing field creates a large imbalance between the affected contractors and their competitors.

Proportionality

105 The commissioners do not appear to dispute the test of proportionality put forward by the appellants… The burden of proof is on the member state when seeking to justify a restriction on free movement, to establish that the measure is proportionate.

106 Burton found that the measures were suitable and necessary for the objective pursued and further that it was appropriate for him to consider other less restrictive means of attaining the objective sought by canvassing other possible methods of fiscal reform. The appellants submit that both findings were incorrect.

Suitable and necessary
108 One oft=repeated explanation of the commissioners has been that a worker providing services to a client through a service company who would have been regarded as an employee but for the existence of that company, should be taxed on the same basis as an employee of that company or of a large contracting company.

109 However IR35 is neither a necessary nor a sufficient means of achieving that objective; it goes both too far and not far enough.

110 First, as the appellants have repeatedly explained, the mechanism of IR35 and the commissioners reasoning behind the legislation is based on an incorrect comparison of the gross revenue of a service company from a particular engagement with the salary of an individual employee from the same engagement.

111. However the commissioners logic – and the conclusions drawn from it in the mechanics of IR35 – is utterly flawed and demonstrates a fundamental misunderstanding of the workings of small businesses.

112 The result is that far from achieving tax neutrality between a worker of a service company and an employee, IR35 renders the tax liability in respect of the workers significantly greater than the tax liability in respect of an employee.

114 … if the revenue’s concern is to ensure that employment-like services should be taxed under Schedule E, then IR35 falls FAR SHORT of that aim, since it excludes the many engagements undertaken by employees of large service providers, which would equally have been employment had there been a direct contract between the worker and the client.

115 The commissioners only answer to this is that this leaves out of account the governments intention to address situations where a single worker can influence what happens to money received by his employer for work he has done. If that was the intention, however, IR35 equally does not achieve that. The provisions do not, anywhere, include a test , of whether a worker on a particular engagement can influence the direction of fees from that engagement. Rather the provisions refer to an entirely different test of whether the worker has a 5% or more shareholding in the company.

116 … Far from presenting a coherent, logical and proportionate response to a defined problem, the 5% “material interest” test sets an arbitrary threshold which has little or no correlation with the purported aim of the legislation.

Least restrictive: judges wrong approach

117 Burton declined to consider the question of whether the IR35 measures were in fact the least restrictive means of achieving the aims sought. This was however contrary to the requirements of a national court considering the proportionality test.

118 Moreover as the European Court has recently stated … the rigorous requirements of proportionality apply even in the fiscal sphere.

119 It follows that while Burton did not have to opine on the appropriateness or otherwise of specific alternative fiscal means available to the government, he DID have to decide under the principle of proportionality whether the commissioners had demonstrated that IR35 was the least restrictive means available to achieve whatever aim was put forward.

120 The commissioners in their skeleton argument do not even attempt to address this serious error. Their only comment is that the appellants had failed in any event to identify any realistic alternative…

121 However

a) It is not for the appellants to identify a realistic alternative. As set out above the burden of proof is on the Commissioners…
b) The Commissioners noticeably fail to mention in their list of possible alternative measures the suggestion by the Appellants of payment of a minimum salary before dividends became payable. The Commissioners response to this suggestion in the witness statement of Sarah Walker was that it would have been unfair to specify a single minimum salary which would cover the range of occupations where service companies are used. However, Sarah Walker goes on to admit that IR35 “does require a minimum payment of tax and NICs based on the assumption of a minimum salary (though it does not require any amount of salary to be paid)”. This admission which betrays the truth of IR35; that it bases income tax and NICs on an assumption of a salary equivalent to 95 per cent of fee income, regardless of the true requirements and expenses of the service company and entirely regardless of whether or not that salary has been paid. The Commissioners have not even started to explain how a measure this onerous and unfair could be the least restrictive means available to them to combat any perceived tax avoidance.

Last update: Wed Dec 5 15:08:10 2001